首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   297篇
  免费   55篇
  国内免费   7篇
  2024年   1篇
  2022年   3篇
  2021年   5篇
  2020年   10篇
  2019年   5篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   12篇
  2015年   18篇
  2014年   19篇
  2013年   66篇
  2012年   20篇
  2011年   15篇
  2010年   18篇
  2009年   18篇
  2008年   15篇
  2007年   22篇
  2006年   8篇
  2005年   13篇
  2004年   13篇
  2003年   17篇
  2002年   17篇
  2001年   13篇
  2000年   5篇
  1999年   6篇
  1998年   3篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   1篇
  1990年   2篇
  1988年   1篇
  1986年   1篇
排序方式: 共有359条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
81.
在空间预警系统中,为了降低系统预警精度受视线测量系统误差的影响,必须对仪器进行定标,因此需要深入对视线误差进行讨论。本文在对视线误差深入研究的基础上,从理论上讨论了视线误差对发射点、射向、落点估计结果的影响,得出系统误差变化率是影响预警结果的重要因素之一,并针对常值系统误差、线性系统误差以及周期系统误差进行了相应的预警仿真计算,从而为几何定标方案的确定提供支持。  相似文献   
82.
盛辉辉 《国防科技》2010,31(5):34-39
新颁布的《国防动员法》为我国今后军事征用活动的开展提供了重要的法律依据,是军事征用法制发展的里程碑。文章提出,与现行军事征用的立法价值实现及实践要求相比,我国军事征用法律制度仍存在需要完善之处。应科学设立军事征用主体、不断完善军事征用程序和军事征用补偿机制。  相似文献   
83.
While accepting consumer returns has long been proposed as a solution to resolve the consumer valuation uncertainty problem, there are still a sizable portion of retailers who insist on a “no return” policy. In this article, we offer an economic rationale for these seemingly unreasonable strategies in a supply chain context. We demonstrate when and why the retailer may benefit from refusing consumer returns, even though offering consumer returns allows the supply chain to implement the expostmarket segmentation. Granting the retailer the right to refuse consumer returns may sometimes improve supply chain efficiency: it eliminates the manufacturer's attempt to induce inefficient consumer returns and bring the equilibrium back to that in the vertically integrated benchmark. We also find that the refund and the retail price can move in the opposite directions when product reliability varies, and consumer returns have a nontrivial impact on the quality choice. © 2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Naval Research Logistics 62: 686–701, 2015  相似文献   
84.
We consider a three‐layer supply chain with a manufacturer, a reseller, and a sales agent. The demand is stochastically determined by the random market condition and the sales agent's private effort level. Although the manufacturer is uninformed about the market condition, the reseller and the sales agent conduct demand forecasting and generate private demand signals. Under this framework with two levels of adverse selection intertwined with moral hazard, we study the impact of the reseller's and the sales agent's forecasting accuracy on the profitability of each member. We show that the manufacturer's profitability is convex on the reseller's forecasting accuracy. From the manufacturer's perspective, typically improving the reseller's accuracy is detrimental when the accuracy is low but is beneficial when it is high. We identify the concrete interrelation among the manufacturer‐optimal reseller's accuracy, the volatility of the market condition, and the sales agent's accuracy. Finally, the manufacturer's interest may be aligned with the reseller's when only the reseller can choose her accuracy; this alignment is never possible when both downstream players have the discretion to choose their accuracy. © 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Naval Research Logistics 61: 207–222, 2014  相似文献   
85.
This article compares the profitability of two pervasively adopted return policies—money‐back guarantee and hassle‐free policies. In our model, a seller sells to consumers with heterogeneous valuations and hassle costs. Products are subject to quality risk, and product misfit can only be observed post‐purchase. While the hassle‐free policy is cost advantageous from the seller's viewpoint, a money‐back guarantee allows the seller to fine‐tune the consumer hassle on returning the product. Thus, when the two return policies lead to the same consumer behaviors, the hassle‐free policy dominates. Conversely, a money‐back guarantee can be more profitable even if on average, high‐valuation consumers experience a lower hassle cost than the low‐valuation ones. The optimal hassle cost can be higher when product quality gets improved; thus, it is not necessarily a perfect proxy or signal of the seller's quality. We further allow the seller to adopt a mixture of these policies, and identify the concrete operating regimes within which these return policies are optimal among more flexible policies. © 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Naval Research Logistics 61: 403–417, 2014  相似文献   
86.
We study a supply chain in which an original equipment manufacturer (OEM) and a contract manufacturer (CM) compete in the finished goods market. The OEM can decide whether to outsource the intermediate good, a critical component for producing the finished good, from the CM or make in‐house production. Technology transition improves the CM's production efficiency, and it can take two different forms: a direct technology transfer from the OEM to the CM or technology spillovers through outsourcing from the OEM to the CM. We document the possibility of strategic outsourcing, that is, the CM supplies the intermediate good to the OEM when she is less efficient than the OEM's in‐house production. We find that technology spillovers can strengthen the incentive for strategic outsourcing. Furthermore, compared with direct technology transfers, outsourcing coupled with technology spillovers may generate more technology transition. Outsourcing is a particularly appropriate channel for implicit collusion when the OEM is not very efficient with the production of the intermediate good. Our results suggest that ex post competition on the finished goods can create room for ex ante collaboration and provide some implications on the OEM's outsourcing strategies when facing a competitive CM.© 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Naval Research Logistics 61: 501–514, 2014  相似文献   
87.
FQPSK-JR和SOQPSK-TG是IRIG-106遥测标准中可以互换的两种信号体制,两种信号有着近乎相同的功率效率和带宽效率。尽管两种信号都可以采用常规的OQPSK接收机进行解调,但是基于OQPSK结构的接收机忽略了两种信号固有的记忆特性,其解调性能损失相比最优解调达2dB之多。在遥测链路中,受设备体积及电源限制,2dB的功率损失是至关重要的。虽然基于其调制体制相对应的最优接收机都能提高功率效率,但信号产生体制的不同导致了其对应的最优接收机结构不同。将IRIG-106标准中的FQPSK-JR信号用CPM调制来近似表示,将SOQPSK-TG信号的频率成型脉冲进行了截短近似,设计了基于CPM的通用准最优解调器。基于CPM近似设计出的解调器与OQPSK解调器一样无须对两种信号进行识别,仿真表明基于CPM设计的通用解调器对两种信号进行解调的渐进损失都很小,对复杂度也进行了分析对比。  相似文献   
88.
Hatzinikolaou raises a number of issues related mainly to the econometrics of our paper. These issues are categorized according to the three stages of econometric analysis: specification, estimation, and diagnostic checking. We categorize our reply to his comments accordingly.  相似文献   
89.
This paper employs both linear and non‐linear models to investigate the relationship between national defense spending and economic growth for Taiwan and China. Using data from 1953–2000 on defense spending, GDP, import, export and capital, we find that China's defense spending leads that of Taiwan. There exists the phenomenon of an arms race between both countries when official Chinese data are used. On the one hand, feedback relations prevail between economic growth and defense spending growth in Taiwan. On the other hand, China's national defense is found to lead economic growth.  相似文献   
90.
We model an oppressor aiming at victimizing an excluded group in his country, with two main variants. A foreign power affects his behaviour using either conditional aid, subject to the dictator’s participation constraint, or the threat of sanctions, broadly defined, subject to the credibility constraint. The choice between the two is either determined by the latter, or by their relative cost. Aid is preferred when the threat of sanctions is ineffective, and sanctions are too expensive. Sanctions might be imposed, if the threat is ineffective. A case study of the Iraqi Kurds after Iraq was subject to sanctions is presented.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号